The very talented Steve Blank has laid out a case for why U.S. academic research is in serious trouble based on recent U.S. policy changes. As he states, once you lose your advantage it's unlikely to be regained. My guess is that there's a certain point at which the lead is lost and is too difficult to regain. A March 2025 Nature article reports on a poll which indicates that of 1,600 scientists surveyed around 75% are contemplating moving with Canada or Europe as top destinations. I wonder what unintended consequences--particularly those that are beneficial for the United States--may exist in distributing U.S. researchers around the world. Could they be lured back in three years and seven months? And, what could be some unintended negative consequences? Do we really want to lose our best researchers during a military build-up around the world? Gee whiz, it seems like almost everything is a national security issue and all technology is dual use. Steve Blank's blog post is available, here.
"Where money issues meet IP rights". This weblog looks at financial issues for intellectual property rights: securitisation and collateral, IP valuation for acquisition and balance sheet purposes, tax and R&D breaks, film and product finance, calculating quantum of damages--anything that happens where IP meets money.
Wednesday, 14 May 2025
Steve Blank Sounds Warning for U.S. Academic Research Decline
Thursday, 3 April 2025
Bad Timing: Starving the University Technology Transfer System
A group of over 1000 scientists who are elected members of
the National Academy of Sciences, Engineering and Medicine has released a
letter expressing concern with the Trump Administration’s handling of research
funding. The letter states, in part:
If our country’s research enterprise is dismantled, we will
lose our scientific edge. Other countries will lead the development of novel
disease treatments, clean energy sources, and the new technologies of the
future. Their populations will be healthier, and their economies will surpass
us in business, defense, intelligence gathering, and monitoring our planet’s
health. The damage to our nation’s scientific enterprise could take decades to
reverse.
The AUTM, the Association of University Technology Managers,
noted that the Great Recession would have been much worse if it had not been
for university technology transfer. Harming the engine that’s been
creating innovation and new business may not be such a good thing right
now. Besides pushing us into a recession, I do wonder what the political
fallout will be of the increased removal of research funding from universities. Not
only do universities spin-off companies to varying degrees of success but
there are universities located in many, many congressional districts--and those
universities are major regional employers. The full letter is available, here. The
Scientific American discusses the full letter, here.
Friday, 5 April 2024
Japanese Universities Having Trouble with Tech Transfer
Nikkei Asia has published an article by Kenjiru Suzuki titled, "Japan's Universities Fail to Make the Most of Intellectual Property: Due to Lack of Support, Patents Only Make 2% Compared to U.S. Schools." The title provides a nice summary of the article's findings. Research has pointed to differences between countries and their innovation systems as to why a specific country may not experience the relative success of U.S. universities in technology transfer. For example, there may be differences in university culture, laws concerning taking a company public, corporate formation laws, laws concerning mergers and acquisitions, tax law, amount of available funding, expected licensing terms, skilled workforce, specific IP and data rights laws, networks of support and engagement, university researcher buy-in, and availability of capital (among other things). I confess I am surprised that Japan has not realized more success in this area.
Tuesday, 20 February 2024
U.S. FTC Supports March-in Rights Guidelines
The U.S. Federal Trade Commission has released a comment in support of the NIST’s guidelines concerning the exercise of march-in rights under the Bayh-Dole Act. The Press Release states:
Today the Federal Trade Commission issued
a comment in response to the National Institute of Standards and
Technology’s (NIST) request for information on its Draft Interagency Guidance
Framework for Considering the Exercise of March-In Rights under the Bayh-Dole
Act.
Under the Bayh-Dole Act, the federal government has the right
to “march in” on patents on inventions created using taxpayer funds—to require
the patent holder to license the federally funded patent to other applicants.
The draft interagency framework provides guidance outlining when the government
should exercise its march-in rights, which have never before been utilized. The
draft framework makes clear that high price is an appropriate basis for
exercising march-in rights.
In the comment, the FTC applauds NIST, which is part of the
U.S. Department of Commerce, and the Interagency Working Group for Bayh-Dole,
which includes the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, for their
efforts to reactivate march-in rights as an important check on companies
charging Americans inflated prices for drugs developed with taxpayer-funded
research. In the comment, the FTC expressed support for an expansive and
flexible approach to march-in rights, including providing that agencies can march
in on the basis of high prices.
The FTC’s comment draws on its experience in promoting
competition and combatting anticompetitive practices in the pharmaceuticals
industry. Lack of competition in pharmaceutical markets can lead to inflated
pricing, rendering some lifesaving treatments out of reach for many Americans.
Nearly three in 10 Americans report rationing or skipping their medications due
to high costs. Contrary to industry claims that high drug prices are necessary
to fund research and development (R&D), drug prices often depend more on
whether the drug faces competition than the drug’s R&D costs. At the same
time, pharmaceutical firms enjoy hundreds of billions of dollars of taxpayer
investment in R&D. March-in rights are an essential check to ensure that
taxpayer-funded inventions are affordable and accessible to the public.
The FTC’s comment further explains that although march-in
rights can be a valuable tool to address potential harms in the pharmaceutical
industry, broader challenges requiring government-wide solutions remain. For
example, dense “patent thickets” result from pharmaceutical companies using
increasingly large patent portfolios to protect a single treatment. This may
weaken the utility of march-in rights to provide affordable public access to
drugs because some pharmaceuticals may be protected by patent thickets
that include privately funded blocking patents in addition to government-funded
patents subject to march-in rights. In its comment, the FTC urges
agencies to work collaboratively to also address such patent thickets.
The Commission voted 3-0 to approve filing of the comment.
Monday, 11 December 2023
The Exercise of Bayh-Dole March-in Rights Coming Soon?
The U.S. Department of Commerce, National Institute of Standards and Technology has released a proposed framework for analyzing whether march-in rights under the Bayh-Dole Act should be exercised. Notably, march-in rights have never been exercised. A concern is that exercise of the rights could create a disincentive for companies to invest in commercializing government funded inventions. Additionally, there is a concern that basing the exercise of march-in rights on pricing concerns will be particularly harmful. The proposed framework can be found, here. There is a comment period as well. The proposed framework contains several Scenarios with a sample analysis of the problem. All of the Scenarios are worth reviewing, but I found 5 and 6 to be particularly interesting. The following includes the analysis under Scenario 5 and 6:
Scenario 5
Background: A water filtration company has an
exclusive license from a government-funded university to patents covering a
subject invention for point-of-use water purification technology. The company
manufactures a small device, which can be used to remove organic contaminants
like pesticides in households that get their drinking water from wells. Ten
years ago, a certain pesticide became very popular because it was safe for
native U.S. pollinators but effective at combatting an invasive beetle
destroying crops nationwide. But recent studies have shown a ten-fold increase
in pediatric cancers that is connected to drinking groundwater contaminated
with that pesticide. The water filtration company's point-of-use purification
device is uniquely able to remove even trace amounts of that pesticide. As a
result, demand has spiked. However, the company has not increased its
manufacturing pace, so the price of the devices has jumped 1000% in the past
three months. The combination of the limited supply and increased prices has resulted
in a health emergency that cannot be adequately addressed without expanding
capacity. Three other manufacturers and a dozen rural community groups have
asked the government funding agency to march-in and issue licenses to increase
supply and reduce cost of the specialized filters.
Discussion: Given the pressing need, march-in would be
among a range of options the agency would likely consider for resolving this
problem promptly and protecting children.
Statutory Criteria —In this scenario, it appears that
march-in may alleviate a health or safety need that, at this time, is not
reasonably being satisfied by the contractor or its licensee (Statutory
Criterion 2). First, the agency would seek to confirm underlying information,
including about the health or safety need. For example, the agency would
consult with experts and appropriate agencies, seek available information about
how the pesticide contributes to pediatric cancer, and investigate how (and how
effectively) this purification device removes the pesticide (Statutorily
Defined March-In Criteria; Criterion 2; Sections I–III). The agency would also
confirm basic facts with the contractor, including whether it is refusing to
ramp up manufacturing and how much the price has increased. All of this would
be with an eye toward mitigating the risk of pediatric cancer, which in this
scenario would appear to require an increased supply and accessible filtration
devices (Section IV). The agency would likely assess whether the contractor is
in fact exploiting the health or safety need to set a product price that is
egregious within the U.S. market and unjustified given the totality of
circumstances (Section IV, E). If the evidence suggests this 1000% increase was
an intentional act by the company to “cash-in” on this newly discovered health
and safety need, that would weigh in favor of march-in. However, if the entire
market has seen similar price increases and there is a compelling justification
for such a high price, e.g., a shortage of essential raw materials is
making increased production impossible, that would weigh against march-in.
Policy & Objectives of Bayh-Dole —The agency would
similarly need to assess the practical impact of march-in on the unmet need and
carefully evaluate all alternatives (Would March-In Support the Policy &
Objective of Bayh-Dole). For example, if the pesticide stays in the water supply
long term and there's no indication other solutions will become available very
soon, that would weigh in favor of march-in. If farmers are no longer using the
pesticide in question and it dissipates quickly, then the demand for filters
could subside soon, weighing against march-in. Additionally, the fact that
there are already other interested manufacturers suggests march-in could
increase production by these entities soon, weighing in favor of march-in.
However, the agency would need to examine the capability of the prospective
licensees and manufacturers and be comfortable these are “reasonable
applicants” that could get a product to market (Section I, E). Here again, the
agency would also consider possible alternatives, like other technologies to
protect children (Section II). For example, perhaps another agency has already
banned the pesticide and that, combined with an alternative filtration
technology, could bring the pesticide levels to a safe percentage within the
year, weighing against march-in. Finally, the agency would analyze the wider
implications of march-in to ensure consistency with Bayh-Dole policy and
objectives (Section III). The agency may determine that exercising march-in
rights would have a meaningful positive impact on child health, increase
confidence that federally funded inventions are available to improve the lives
of Americans, result in increased competition, and set an example of actions by
contractors or licensees that are “off limits.” The agency may determine those
factors outweigh any negative impacts on investments in future federal R&D,
given the apparent bad-faith actions of the contractor (Sections III, A, 2;
III, 3).
Scenario 6
Background: In the early stages of a respiratory virus
pandemic, a consumer goods company working under a government contract
developed improved face masks that filter out 99% of that virus' particles. The
contractor filed for a patent on its mask technology, and it reported the
subject invention and associated patent application to the government. During a
three-week window, several experts published studies confirming that the virus
spreads easily and rapidly through airborne transmission. The following week,
the consumer goods company increased the price of its masks 100%, and it
continued to raise the price over the course of a month, resulting in a 400%
price increase. The company has also sent letters to other mask manufacturers,
flagging the pending patent application and promising to file lawsuits against
any infringers as soon as the patent issues. Trade associations representing
frontline healthcare workers asked the government funding agency to march-in
and issue licenses to those other manufacturers to bring down the price of the
masks.
Discussion: Given the urgent need, march-in would be
among a range of options the agency would likely consider for resolving this
problem promptly and protecting frontline workers.
Statutory Criteria —In this scenario, it appears there
could be actions that promote nonuse or unreasonable use of the subject
invention (Criterion 1) as well as health and safety needs that are not being
reasonably satisfied by the contractor (Statutory Criterion 2). The agency
would first ask the contractor for information to confirm the basic facts—for
example, that the contractor has increased price 400%, how that increase
compares to prices for other masks, how that price point compares to the cost
of developing and manufacturing the masks, that the contractor has filed for
patents, and that it is threatening to file suit against competing
manufacturers when a patent issues. Based on that, the agency could continue
its inquiry to assess whether march-in would alleviate an unmet health need
and/or ensure the benefits of the mask are available to the public on
reasonable terms, exploring questions detailed in Statutorily Defined March-In
Criteria; Criterion 1 and 2. In this scenario, more affordable masks are needed
and it may be that more mask production would bring down the price (Section
III; IV, E). The agency would likely need more information to assess whether
the contractor is exploiting the health or safety need in setting a product
price that is egregious within the U.S. market and unjustified given the
totality of circumstances and/or whether the masks are available on reasonable
terms (Section IV, E). By rapidly increasing the price of masks and threatening
other manufacturers with litigation during an urgent public health need, the
contractor seems focused on keeping prices unusually high while not satisfying
demand. This could weigh in favor of march-in. But the agency would need
additional information, for example, to understand the unmet need, how march-in
would impact it, and why the contractor is responding this way. Are other mask
manufacturers charging similarly high prices under the circumstances, all to
fund facility expansion? If so, that would weigh against march-in (Section IV,
E). Is there a strong connection between mask usage (or mask availability) and
public health benefit? Does this mask provide unique benefits over others?
Stronger evidence the masks resolve a health need could weigh more in favor of
march-in, whereas tangential evidence of unique benefits could weigh against
march-in (Section III). Is there a legitimate reason not to license other
manufacturers for this mask, e.g., they lack capacity or capability?
Answers to those questions could justify the contractor's actions and weigh
against march-in (Section IV, E).
Policy & Objectives of Bayh-Dole —The first part
of this analysis looks at whether march-in would promote utilization and
protect against non-use of the subject invention (Would March-In Support The
Policy & Objective Of Bayh-Dole Section I). The agency would need to
understand whether other manufacturers are “responsible applicants” that would
be interested and willing to make the masks in question (Section I, E). The
agency would also likely want to understand the impact of the pending patent
application and threat of (possible) litigation on the other manufacturers (I,
B; II, E). If the other manufacturers are actually deterred from making the
product, then that could weigh in favor of march-in. However, if other
manufacturers do not believe valid patents are going to issue on this subject
invention, and those manufacturers are willing to immediately start
manufacturing masks, that could weigh against march-in. The agency would also
consider whether other action might be warranted—for example, the agency
purchasing or manufacturing the masks itself at a lower price (Section II, A).
Whether march-in would protect the public against non-use or unreasonable use
of subject inventions more broadly likely depends on similar facts (Section
III). However, in a situation of a pressing health or safety need, where a
contractor is artificially keeping supply low while demand for a product is
high or artificially increasing the price, march-in could deter others from
similar actions in the future without impacting contractors and licensees who
act in good faith to bring products to market and meet market demand (Section
III, A, 2).
Monday, 14 March 2022
A Compelling Read: New Yorker Article on the U.S. Department of Justice's "China Initiative"
The New Yorker has published an important, fascinating and excellent article concerning Franklin Tao, a university researcher, who was caught up in the U.S. Department of Justice's China Initiative. The article is titled, "Have Chinese Spies Infiltrated American Campuses," and is authored by Gideon Lewis-Kraus. The article mostly focuses on Mr. Tao's experience, but also raises numerous important questions about the Trump Administration's China Initiative and its general approach. Notably, the Biden Administration has discontinued that initiative, but see here on addressing "The PRC Threat." The article may be classified as additional proof under the Trump Administration critique: "Can Spot a Problem, But Proposes Unworkable and Likely Ultimately Unproductive Solutions." The article could focus a bit more on how in some technical fields the line between basic and applied research is blurred. Additionally, the question of industry competitiveness (and dare I say protection) is an important one that has national security implications--especially in a global economy. This is particularly true where private interests control a significant amount of critical (and other) infrastructure and national governments spend significant amounts of funding on research and development that leads to economic development. It is important to remember that many universities in the United States are land grant institutions with direction to help develop local economic interests. The Bayh-Dole Act itself points toward a preference for U.S. economic development. Moreover, democracy relies upon the trust and the relative prosperity of many of its citizens (the protection of good paying middle class jobs). The article seems to indicate that the big difference between now and past policy concerning approaches to sharing technology with, for example, the Soviet Union, is that the United States is no longer perceived as being "on top." There may be some truth to that, but I don't think it is the full story: a lot has happened since then besides that fear. The important recommended article is available, here. I hope it stimulates more thought and conversation.
Thursday, 20 May 2021
mRNA Vaccine Patents Study
Mario Gaviria and Burcu Kilic have published an interesting article titled, “A Network Analysis of Covid-19 mRNA Vaccine Patents.” The article helpfully provides information concerning the relationship between entities, patents and licenses concerning mRNA vaccine patents. Notably, the article identifies foundational patents from the University of Pennsylvania and the University of British Columbia and traces the relationship through various entities. The article is available, here. KEI provides an analysis of potential U.S. government funding of some of those patents, here.
Wednesday, 13 January 2021
Regulatory Changes Coming to the Bayh-Dole Act Regs?: Free Webinar
UIDP is holding a free webinar at 9:00 am Pacific Standard Time on January 14, 2021. The webinar is titled, “Implementation of the NIST ROI Green Paper Findings.” The description states:
Based on input from thousands of organizations in the
research community, the National Institute of Standards and Technology (NIST)
has recommended legislative changes to dramatically increase the ROI from the
billions in government investment in research and development. This webinar
will showcase the pending changes and provide information on the new
opportunities and streamlined processes for universities and businesses that
interact with federal labs or receive federal funding. The implications of the
changes for research organizations both in the U.S. and abroad are significant.
Background: In April 2019, the National Institute of
Standards and Technology (NIST) announced the release of a final green paper
from its Return on Investment (ROI) Initiative for Unleashing American
Innovation. This national goal aims to dramatically increase returns from the
more than $150 billion per year of U.S. federal government investment in
research and development. The NIST ROI Green Paper provided a summary of
private and public stakeholder inputs received from hundreds of experts and
organizations representing thousands of companies, universities, federal
laboratories and other institutions. The document identified 15 findings by
NIST to help inform decision-making and implementing actions by the relevant
departments and agencies that could further enhance the U.S. innovation engine
at the public-private interface. A number of the findings noted that
implementation would require revisions to the Stevenson-Wydler Technology
Innovation Act of 1980 or the implementing regulations to the Bayh-Dole Act. In
response, NIST has vetted through informal and formal interagency processes and
delivered both a legislative proposal containing 10 findings for modernizing
the Stevenson-Wydler Act, and a Notice of Proposed Rulemaking for updates to
the Bayh-Dole Act regulations.
The speaker is Courtney Silverthorn, the Acting Director of
the Technology Partnerships Office at the National Institutes of Standards. The moderator is Jay Schrankler, the Associate
Vice President and Head of Polsky Center for Entrepreneurship & Innovation,
University of Chicago. Registration
information is available, here.
Wednesday, 26 February 2020
Extra Protection for the Bayh-Dole Act Needed in the United States?
Bayh-Dole 40 is a new coalition of supporters of the landmark legislation concerning technology transfer—the Bayh-Dole Act. The Bayh-Dole 40 has an attractive website with information concerning the history of the Act and its impact. The press release states:
It is interesting that the existence of the coalition is necessary to protect the Bayh-Dole Act. There is some polling to support that U.S. Senator Bernie Sanders could defeat President Trump in an election, but I wonder if anyone really believes that polling (besides Sanders supporters) after the results of the last Presidential election. Maybe the concern will be what happens in the election after this one.
Friday, 18 October 2019
Improving the Allocation of Resources: Artificial Intelligence to Predict Future Clinical Success of Basic Research
In a new paper published on October 10, 2019 titled, “Predicting Translational Progress in Biomedical Research,” authors B. Ian Hutchins, Matthew T. Davis, Rebecca A. Meseroll, and George M. Santangelo describe a new way to use artificial intelligence to measure and predict which basic research type findings are likely to be translated into clinical advances. The abstract states:
The full paper is available, here. This appears to have the promise of mitigating some significant investment risk.
Monday, 29 April 2019
The U.S. National Institute of Standards and Technology Green Paper on Improving Technology Transfer
Tuesday, 28 February 2017
A Closer Look at CRISPR Patents and Licensing: A More Nuanced Approach
Monday, 27 February 2017
US Senate Candidate in California Critical of Bayh-Dole Act
Friday, 23 December 2016
Association of University Technology Managers Releases FY 2015 Highlights Report
Wednesday, 20 July 2016
Redistribution of Wealth Through Giving and the Bayh-Dole Act
The Bayh-Dole Act (and general U.S. federal policy) operates to redistribute wealth from tax payers to universities, non-profits and companies through their ability to take title to government funded inventions. Essentially, tax payers pay money to the government. Instead of that money getting redistributed through social programs or other means, the money is distributed in the form of grants for research to universities, non-profits and companies. The Bayh-Dole Act then allows those entities to take title to any inventions developed from that money. Part of the rationale for the Bayh-Dole Act, along with the incentive to commercialize theory, is to ensure that private industry has the incentive to bring government funded technology to market--to cross the so-called "valley of death". As the story goes, prior to passage of the Bayh-Dole Act, many government funded inventions "languished" on the shelf of the government. Many believe the Bayh-Dole Act is an inspired piece of legislation. Indeed, many countries around the world have passed similar laws to harness the power of government funded invention.
Interestingly, the Association of University Technology Managers (AUTM) pointed to a potential silver lining, of sorts, in the Great Recession. Universities continued to spin out companies (and apparently create good paying jobs) based on university developed technology during the Great Recession. If not for the Bayh-Dole Act, the Great Recession might have been much worse for the United States.
I was listening to National Public Radio (NPR) the other day and noticed that the Lemelson Foundation was supporting NPR. The Lemelson Foundation was started by Dorothy Lemelson, the famous inventor Jerry Lemelson's wife. The Foundation supports invention and commercialization efforts primarily through education in the United States and in other countries. Specifically, the Foundation appears to focus on college-aged possible inventors and addressing the needs of the poor through invention. The Foundation reached its 20th anniversary this year and there is an interesting list of its achievements and activities, here.
Notably, Jerry Lemelson was well-known for his patenting/invention activity--over 600 patents. He was also well-known for his assertion of patents (submarine patents as they were known) against practicing companies, particularly for his "scanner" technology. Interestingly, Wikipedia notes that he extracted about $1.3 billion in licenses from companies. When examining the merits of a particular practice--let's say so-called patent trolling, perhaps we should also look to the uses that some monies made from that activity are used, including voluntary redistribution.