Valerie Landrio McDevitt, Joelle Mendez-Hinds, David Winwood,
Vinit Nijhawan,Todd Sherer, John F. Ritter, and Paul R. Sanberg, have authored
a paper titled, “More than Money: The Exponential Impact of Academic Technology Transfer.” The paper sets forth the
benefits of technology transfer beyond revenue alone and perhaps provides the
starting point for the development of additional metrics to judge the success
of technology transfer offices. Here are
the benefits described by the authors:
Revenue generation
Unrestricted funds to institution from
license income
Direct personal financial benefit to
inventors and authors
Increased opportunities
for funding
Eligibility for funding by compliance with federal
regulations requiring a technology transfer program
Increased opportunities for
interinstitutional and interdisciplinary grants
Outreach, licensing, and facilitation of new startups yield
new funding partnerships
Increased opportunities for funding sources requiring a commercial
partner, for example, SBIR and STTR
Facilitates establishment of international research
relationships
Promotes a culture of entrepreneurship and innovation
Successes increase university brand and
prestige
Enhances university fundraising efforts
Opportunities to strengthen donor ties by
engagement with startups
Positively factors into high level
recruitment efforts
Positively affects retention of
high-producing and high-potential faculty
Student success
Provides opportunities to participate in
real world translational research
Provides exposure to the process of
obtaining intellectual property protection
Strengthens prospects of finding jobs and
being successful
Public benefit
Fulfills the university’s larger missions to address social,
medical, environmental, or technical problems
Improves the quality of life
Economic development
Revenue from university licensing positively
affects the US economy
Brings money into the state or region
Aids in the retention of local talent
New university startups create high-wage
jobs
It may be difficult to measure
some of these “benefits.” But, what do
you think of some of these as potential metrics? For sure,
some of the most beneficial programs often bring to the table attributes that are
difficult to measure. And, surely, metrics
such as revenue generation, invention disclosures, patents granted, patents
applied for, patents licensed, number of start-ups and other traditional
metrics still have some place in the game.
(Hat tip to Technology Transfer Tactics for a lead to the paper.)
1 comment:
This is, as you highlight at the beginning of the post, a controversial area because so few university tech transfer offices break even. The McDevitt paper does not address that issue and is really one-sided support for university tech transfer. What we need is an unbiased objective appraisal of why tech transfer offices fail so often. I suspect it's because only particular types of research can be commercialised. For example follow on research (where patent claims of narrow scope would be obtained) may not be suitable, and if a research team or university is doing a lot of that then perhaps it's better not to attempt tech transfer. I think if a tech transfer office cannot break even something is seriously wrong and the metrics which the paper describes don't help in sorting things out. The US has the most data and the most experience with university tech transfer. They are most likely to solve its problems, but first those problems have to be acknowledged properly.
Post a Comment