According to research published by J.
Gregory Sidak of Criterion Economics, the process by which the Institute of
Electrical and Electronics Engineers (IEEE) amended its patent policy was
significantly biased in favour of implementers and against standard-essential
patent (SEP) owners.
Sidak provides a succinct description
of the patent policy amendments and finds that these limit the ability of SEP
owners to generate patent licensing royalties.
“In 2015, the IEEE ratified amendments to its patent policy to
mandate that a reasonable and nondiscriminatory (RAND) royalty for a
standard-essential patent (SEP)—more precisely, an Essential Patent Claim for
an IEEE standard—exclude any value attributable to the standard, and to deny an
SEP holder the right to seek an injunction against an unlicensed implementer
until appellate review is exhausted. The amendments further say that the
determination of a RAND royalty “should,” without limitation, (1) be derived
from the value of the smallest salable compliant implementation of an IEEE
standard that practices an SEP; (2) comport with a reasonable aggregate
royalty burden of the relevant standard; and (3) disregard comparable
license agreements obtained under the implicit or explicit threat of an
injunction. Because the revisions place strict limitations on an SEP holder’s
ability to enforce its patent rights against infringers, they truncate the
upper range of the distribution of bilaterally negotiated RAND royalties and
thus unambiguously reduce the compensation that the SEP holder may obtain for
its technological contributions to the IEEE standards. The IEEE’s patent-policy
revisions became effective in March 2015.
The IEEE’s 2015 bylaw amendments are highly significant because
each unambiguously reduces the compensation that an SEP holder can obtain for
its technological contributions to the IEEE’s standards. Throughout the
development of those bylaw amendments, sixteen companies submitted 680 comments
on four drafts of the proposed amendments and two drafts of a supporting
informational document that an ad
hoc drafting committee of the
IEEE released for public comment. The ad
hoc committee responded to the suggested revisions in each comment, either
accepting them and implementing them into the next draft, accepting them in
principle, or rejecting them. I find a strong negative correlation between the
comment submitter’s status as a firm initially opposed to the revisions (a
group primarily consisting of net SEP licensors) and the ad hoc committee’s incorporation of the
submitter’s proposed revision in the subsequently revised draft. The treatment
of the comments by the ad hoc committee exhibits a statistically
significant bias against the firms that opposed the bylaw amendments—primarily
large SEP holders—and in favor of revisions designed to devalue SEPs.”
He finds disregard for important principles
and safeguards that IEEE upholds in standard setting. He notes that various
members complained that the process by which the IEEE amended its patent policy
did not comply with the principles of openness, consensus, balance, due
process, and right to appeal that are consistent with the IEEE’s
standard-setting process, and that the ad
hoc drafting committee responsible for the patent policy revisions did not
conciliate this dissent.
“The IEEE patent policy, contained
within the IEEE Standards Board bylaws, specifies the conditions under which an
SEP holder voluntarily commits
to license its SEPs on RAND terms. The bylaws serve as the Standards Board’s
constitution and establish the consensus-driven process of developing and
promulgating technical standards, including the popular 802.11 Wi-Fi standard. Embedded in the bylaws, as well as in
other IEEE governance documents, are comprehensive safeguards that discourage
opportunistic, anticompetitive conduct within the IEEE.”
Also according to Sidak:
“[t]he
2015 bylaw amendments deviated from the safeguards that the IEEE had
guaranteed its members in both the foundational documents of the IEEE and its
history of consensus-driven policymaking.”
Although amending an SDO’s patent
policy is a different process to selecting a technology to incorporate in a
standard, it defies logic or probity that an SDO espousing these principles in
standard setting should abandon them in amending patent policy – something that
is so fundamental to an SDO’s standing and workings.
Sidak identifies self-interest as the
reason the ad hoc committee did this.
“To those large implementers, it is now expedient to
renege on the bargain of interpreting the RAND commitment in a manner that is
neutral to both net licensors and net licensees.” The bias he found in the committee’s
decision making aligns with the company affiliations and employment of committee
voting members and the objectives of those companies:
“the
bias suggests that decision making at the IEEE was controlled by parties that
seek to devalue SEPs. The process for amending the IEEE’s bylaws did not
protect the interests of SEP holders that were disproportionately responsible
for the technologies that the IEEE had incorporated into its standards.”
I wrote, here, prior to its adoption, that the
amended IEEE patent policy was bad policy. I opined it would undermine the free
and fair market for licensing of SEPs and that imposed licensing terms would
make IEEE an unattractive venue for patent owners. Most recently, I have also
written, here, about how interested parties
are also unjustifiably and harmfully trying to foist similar changes on patent
licensing practices more widely.
No comments:
Post a Comment