The IEEE board
of directors is imminently expected (probably on 9th February 2015) to
vote on whether to adopt proposed changes to IP policies which will significantly
diminish the future attractiveness of IEEE as a venue for standards development.
Proposals are fundamentally flawed and have not been properly reviewed in
accordance with IEEE principles and procedures to the point that the European
Commission has publicly expressed its concerns.
In response to a question by
the regulatory newswire MLex, the EC issued this following statement: “The
Commission is closely following the developments at the IEEE. We are very
mindful about the need for a careful balance between guaranteeing full access to
standards at the same time as ensuring appropriate remuneration for
intellectual property. Standards bodies should ensure that their rules comply
with competition law so as to ensure that the benefits of standardisation can
be achieved without anti-competitive outcomes. We are currently running a
public consultation on Standard Essential Patents to gather information and
views on the interplay between standardisation and intellectual property rights
(IPR). The consultation deadline has been extended to 15 February and it would
be premature to draw any conclusions.”
IP policies
are pivotal to standard setting organisations. They determine whether or not
technology developers have sufficient commercial incentives to contribute their
patented technologies and engineering resources in development of
interoperability standards such as IEEE’s 802.11 (WiFi).
Striking a
balance between the interests of developers and implementers of standard-essential
patented technologies is therefore vital. This has been achieved remarkably
well by many SSOs to date including IEEE, ITU and ETSI. WiFi, H.264 video and
GSM/WCDMA are prime examples
of successful global standards from these three SSOs respectively. The proposed rule
changes would likely undermine this success at IEEE.
Unwarranted
changes
Standard
setting IP rules determine the basis upon which implementers inside and outside
SSOs must pay for – in money or in kind – the extensive standard-essential patented
technologies embodied within the standards.
The proposed
policy changes include measures which are dysfunctional, unfair, shun
universally accepted practices or are highly contentious. These include some
measures that undermine IP rights which I have argued against in my previous IP
Finance postings:
·
Defining a
‘reasonable’ royalty using controversial and unworkable valuation
methodologies—including tying a royalty rate to the ‘smallest saleable
component’ of a standard-compliant device—all of which are intended to minimize
licensing fees for SEPs. As I explained
in my IP Finance blog posting entitled Stacking the
Deck in Analysis of Smartphone Patent Licensing Costs, a chip-based royalty scheme incorrectly and
unfairly associates royalties to costs, process economics and competitive
outcomes in the silicon chip foundry manufacturing business that have nothing
to do with mobile technology development costs and the market value generated
from these investments in the broader ecosystem. Similarly, in Commonwealth Scientific and
Industrial Research Organisation versus Cisco Systems, Inc. Judge Leonard Davis ruled that ”It is simply illogical to attempt to
value the contributions of the ’069 Patent based on wireless chip prices that
were artificially deflated because of pervasive infringement. Basing a royalty
solely on chip price is like valuing a copyrighted book based only on the costs
of the binding, paper, and ink needed to actually produce the physical product.
While such a calculation captures the cost of the physical product, it provides
no indication of its actual value.”
·
Severely
limiting injunctive relief available to SEP owners, requiring them to engage in
costly multiyear litigation against infringers who refuse to license an SEP on
reasonable and non-discriminatory terms, and providing them an advantage over
their competitors who are licensed. As I explained in my IP Finance blog
posting entitled Plunging into
a Safe Harbour from SEP Injunctions, reducing the availability of injunction relief for SEPs infringement,
under the threat of antitrust sanction, will unfairly shift the balance of
negotiating power from patentees to licensees. There is no proof that
injunctions unbalance negotiations – especially given that injunctions are very
rarely granted and in the U.S. can be counted on the fingers of one hand. This
shift could undermine royalties and consequently deter further investment in standard-essential
technologies while harm to consumers and licensees is unproven. Some of the
latter are already extremely profitable by exploiting SEPs in conjunction with
their own IP and other competitive strengths.
Violating
values and procedures
In violation with IEEE principles, the proposed
IP policy changes were apparently created by a closed ad-hoc committee that
consistently rejected the repeated and detailed objections, alternative
suggestions, letters of complaint, and appeals of some thirteen respected
technology companies. That is not consistent with openness, due process,
collaboration with all stakeholders, and consensus-based decision making that
SSOs including IEEE purport to uphold. Nor is it consistent with the WTO
criteria that underpin the European standardisation policy. The US Department
of Justice inexplicably glossed over such exclusion in its recent business
review letter.
In March 2013, the IEEE-SA Patent
Committee (“PatCom”) undertook significant substantive changes to the IEEE-SA
Patent Policy. The Ad-Hoc Committee
expressly disclaimed its obligation to respect consensus, and PatCom made no
effort to move the comments and objections toward consensual resolution. Ad Hoc Committee participation
was limited to individuals with an established position of diminishing the
rights of technology holders and requests to participate from individuals with
contrary views were expressly rejected. There has been no attempt to justify
why changes to the Patent Policy are needed and how the proposed changes would
actually address any purported problems or improve standard-setting. The fact
that there exists no legal, regulatory, or economic requirement to make any
changes to the Patent Policy, instead relying on vague and unidentified ‘concerns’
of U.S. and European regulatory officials, has been ignored.
Over approximately fifteen months, the Ad Hoc
Committee published four versions of a revised Patent Policy for comment, but it has systematically
rejected many hundreds of substantive comments and objections to the proposed
Patent Policy changes, often with rote, non-substantive explanations. It has expressly
disclaimed its obligation to respect consensus, and PatCom made no effort to
move the comments and objections toward consensual resolution. Any
deliberations on the comments and objections were closed and no substantive amendments
to the proposed Policy changes were made from the initial draft.
Prejudicial
proceedings
Such is the grave concern that the IEEE board might actually approve the
proposed policy changes, the European Commission (i.e. the EC overall, not a
specific directorate or two therein) at the last minute (4th
February 2015) has issued a formal “Statement.” The EC makes it as clear, as this kind of official
statement ever does, that it is unhappy with developments within the IEEE by:
·
Stating
the EC is ”very mindful” of “the need for a careful balance” between ‘access to
standards” and “ensuring appropriate remuneration for intellectual property”– it is concerned the draft IEEE rules will not
achieve this.
·
Demanding
respect for competition law – with the implication the proposed rules may raise
issues of compliance with European competition Articles. This is presumably on
the basis of the PatCom’s exclusionary conduct and the substantive policy rules
that are reminiscent of a buyer cartel, as well as a forthcoming ruling from
Europe’s Supreme Court on the availability of injunctions.
·
Requesting
the IEEE should not presuppose or prejudice the outcome of the EC’s own reflection
on standardisation and IP (the EC’s public consultation is currently underway with public
comments due on 15th February 2015) that could well go in the
opposite direction to the proposed changes at the IEEE.
Be
careful what you wish (or vote) for
Periodic
policy reviews of SSO rules are desirable and necessary. In the case of ‘open
standards’ it is particularly important that these are undertaken by SSOs in a
transparent manner in which the full range of interests and views are
reflected. Compliance with the law and established SSO principles and operating
procedures is also essential. The best place to start is by asking the
question: are existing policies satisfactory?
If changes are to be made, they should be on the basis of clear evidence
of harm or failure with existing policies and with proof that change will produce
better overall outcomes with fair treatment for various parties who may have
different interests. If not, the rules will impact negatively on those
pro-competitive activities, and will significantly diminish the attractiveness
of SSOs, including IEEE, as standardisation forums.
3 comments:
Update to this post. The IEEE's Board of Governors has approved the policy as can be seen at the following link: https://www.ieee.org/about/news/2015/8_february_2015.html
Too bad. The companies that have made an unrighteous and enormous profit from playing the SSO game in order to fill their corporate treasuries with royalties from SEPs are (finally) encountering pushback. I'm glad to see it.
To argue that the SSO/SEP setup should not be changed because it has been so successful is just another case of the ends justifying the means.
I'm afraid that I don't agree with Anon's comments about unrighteous and enormous profit from playing the SSO game. Many of the participants in the standard setting process invest significant sums in their corporate R&D departments developing technologies, which they then contribute to the standards development process. It's only fair that they see some return on these investments from companies that do not invest in developing the technology.
Post a Comment