(1) . . . expanding on the scholarly debate surrounding
patent trolls; (2) by expanding on the perspectives informing this debate
beyond academia by inviting the views of practitioners from both sides of the
patent troll divide; and (3) by expanding on the scope of this topic by
considering the nature and possibility of copyright and trademark trolls.
I am blogging the conference and here is a partial description of
one of three of the panels. I will also post
partial descriptions of the keynote speaker’s address and the second and third panels soon. For more information about the speakers and the symposium, please use this link. Webcasts of the complete symposium discussion can be found at that link as well. The symposium was organized by Professor Samuel Ernst and the Symposium Editor for the Law Review is Rachel Baker.
The first panel is titled, “The Scholar’s Perspective:
Theories of Patent Trolling.” The
panelists included Robin Feldman, the Harry & Lillian Hastings Professor of
Law and Director of the Institute for Innovation Law at UC Hastings College of
the Law in San Francisco, California; Brian L. Frye, Assistant Professor of
Law, University of Kentucky College of Law; Ryan Holte, Assistant Professor of
Law, Southern Illinois University of Law; and Amy L. Landers, Director of the
Intellectual Property Law Program and Professor of Law, Drexel University
Thomas R. Kline School of Law. The
moderator was Professor Samuel Ernst, Chapman University Fowler School of
Law.
The first panelist to participate was Professor Feldman, who provided a thorough and thoughtful discussion of the patent troll problem and patent reform. Building on and referring to her earlier work, she discusses the Government Accounting Office data concerning non-practicing entities. She notes that the results of this study are similar to other studies, if you include those NPEs organized as trusts. She points to the problem that patent demand letters are very troublesome and account for most of the activity concerning non practicing entitles. However, she states that it is difficult to gather data concerning demand letters and negotiations because they are subject to non-disclosure agreements. She does point to some studies which shed some light as to what is happening with demand letters and subsequent activity that does not result in formal litigation. She outlines how there have been government responses to the nonpracticing entity problem and discusses the Supreme Court cases addressing nonpracticing entities, including the importance of the Alice decision. She looks to the future and notes that, “the rhetoric” is escalating, and expresses concerns about how the Supreme Court is being attacked as “political.” She notes that “in theory” monetization activities can have “positive ends,” but she thinks the way things are happening are not productive. She further notes that smaller firms may suffer the most. She advises turning down the rhetoric and working on the issues.
The first panelist to participate was Professor Feldman, who provided a thorough and thoughtful discussion of the patent troll problem and patent reform. Building on and referring to her earlier work, she discusses the Government Accounting Office data concerning non-practicing entities. She notes that the results of this study are similar to other studies, if you include those NPEs organized as trusts. She points to the problem that patent demand letters are very troublesome and account for most of the activity concerning non practicing entitles. However, she states that it is difficult to gather data concerning demand letters and negotiations because they are subject to non-disclosure agreements. She does point to some studies which shed some light as to what is happening with demand letters and subsequent activity that does not result in formal litigation. She outlines how there have been government responses to the nonpracticing entity problem and discusses the Supreme Court cases addressing nonpracticing entities, including the importance of the Alice decision. She looks to the future and notes that, “the rhetoric” is escalating, and expresses concerns about how the Supreme Court is being attacked as “political.” She notes that “in theory” monetization activities can have “positive ends,” but she thinks the way things are happening are not productive. She further notes that smaller firms may suffer the most. She advises turning down the rhetoric and working on the issues.
Professor Landers asked a fascinating and provocative question of whether patents are the new
bitcoin. She notes that patent monetization
and patent markets have the potential for “positive change,” such as increasing
collaboration internationally in research and pushing funds to research and
development. She notes that
nonpracticing entities are acting rationally in our free market economy. She states that the problem with patents
markets is that there is a “lack of agreement on price.” Thus, “there is a lack of transparency.” She makes the general point that there must
be a valuation of the asset that is credible and transparent, and, in part,
because we lack this there is essentially a “patent bubble.” If this “patent bubble” bursts, then the
entire system is discredited. She
further notes that “a lack of comparables” exist in patent markets similar to
bit coin. She also points to
“nonproportional responses” as “policy bubbles” discussed in sociological
research, that may not provide the benefits that may be expected by
stakeholders and the public. One example
she gives is appointing a czar to address problems. She notes there is not a “widely accepted”
way to value patents – there is “a lack of a fundamental understanding of how
patents are priced.” She notes that the
“price of litigation has nothing to do with the value of the patent” and that
this is a fundamental problem. She
further notes the problem with royalty stacking. She proposes that we move “toward industry
accepted norms for rates” and that we exercise caution with how royalty
rates are set in the future.
Professor Ryan Holte provided a comprehensive and interesting analysis of the MercExchange and eBay
litigation history. His past work has
examined case studies concerning non-practicing entities such as
MercExchange. He reviews the history of
the eBay v. MercExchange case. Notably,
he states that every time a patent case went to the district court judge in the
eBay v. MercExchange litigation, Judge Friedman, he dismissed it—and he
further characterized Judge Friedman’s decisions as “anti-patent owner”. He notes important facts influencing the
case, including eBay’s essentially anti-patent public relations campaign and eBay’s
spin of the Federal Circuit and Supreme Court’s decisions as wins. He points to data after the eBay case and
notes “a huge change” in patent injunctions granted. He notes that the “[p]ost-eBay injunction denial [rate
is] at 78% for NPEs.” He states that “eBay
does not stand for injunctions being unavailable to PAEs—[and that] the true
holding has been lost.” He notes that MercExchange
did win in some ways. He further noted
that district courts tend to overuse the language in Justice Kennedy’s
concurrence concerning NPEs. He also
states that “large notorious public companies are dangerous as litigants for
useful legal precedent.”
Professor Brian L. Frye insightfully stated that metaphors obscure the
problems associated with intellectual property problems. We use many metaphors to describe the scope
of intellectual property, such as “sweat of the brow” or “thieves” or
“bootleggers.” And, finally, “trolls”—entities
that may abuse their rights. He suggests
that dropping metaphors is a good idea for understanding intellectual property,
particularly directed to IP concerned with efficiency justifications. He points out that the problem is poor
patents and the troll metaphor obscures that discussion.
No comments:
Post a Comment