Having not-quite-so-recently received my copy of the March/April issue of
The Patent Lawyer, I rediscovered a piece which I had written for it on patent statistics and what, if anything, they mean, having been slightly inspired by a playful piece of writing by Swiss IP lawyer Mark Schweizer that was hosted on the IPKat,
here. Looking over it, I though I may as well share it with readers of the IP Finance weblog too, since it will surely interest, amuse or irritate some of them. Here it is:
Rich relation, poor relation, correlation
Perhaps because he had nothing
better to do, or possibly because he suspected something, multi-talented Swiss
lawyer and judge Mark Schweizer played around with some official statistics to
see what conclusions they might yield when he matched them against each
other. First he took the per-capita rate
at which patent applications were filed in 19 developed countries (18 European Patent
Organisation members plus the United States). He then plotted the patent filing
rate against the ratio of public debt to gross domestic product (GDP ) in each
of those countries. The result? While
there were a couple of outliers, of which the most significant was patent-rich,
low-debt Switzerland, the general pattern was clear: countries in which public
debt represented a lower proportion of GDP were also those in which the number
of patents filed per capita was higher.
Now, one might seek to explain
these figures in some rational manner, as some commentators have done so; one
might deny the validity of this exercise by sticking to the point that these
figures represent correlation, not causation: one may as well argue that a low
level of public debt is caused by a high level of patent filing activity as the
other way round. In any event, no-one
disagrees that Schweizer’s figures are a snapshot, a view which is based on two
sets of available figures, and that we cannot without further ado establish that
we are staring at a universal truth or even a short-term trend, rather than a
one-off coincidence.
Schweizer’s exercise, which was
never intended as anything other than a good-natured and playful prod at the
patent community, is however important. Within other areas of intellectual property
law, notably copyright, arguments in favour of reform have increasingly been
subjected to the requirement that they be “evidence-based” . The standard of proof is not that of the
courts but that of a cross-disciplinary mix of economics, social psychology,
anthropology and business studies (but not moral philosophy). However, the burden of proof lies with he who
would reform the existing system.
In contrast, while there are
studies a-plenty on the operation of the patent system and its impact in
different industrial sectors, economies and time-frames, the momentum towards
reform in the US, Europe and even China appears to have been the result of a
political push. There may be little or
no harm in this, but every patent system ultimately stands or falls on the
basis of its performance. This need to
appraise a patent system’s performance is something that we are often poor at
recognising, since for so many of us the existence of a patent system is
axiomatic and its form is so closely prescribed by international law. We are
also ill-equipped to carry out the sort of appraisal the patent system needs
since, with differing economic, social, and cultural goals, we cannot easily
agree the criteria by which we must assess it.
This is where the Schweizers of
this world come in. They encourage us through their example to take publicly
available data and use it as a way of reflecting how the patent system performs
relative to other known data. Pegging patent applications to public debt may be
no more meaningful than correlating them to the speed at which patents are
granted, the cost of litigation, the availability of investment funds or
credit, the navigability of corporate red-tape, access to technical data and
assistance, sightings of unidentified flying objects or the national consumption of beer. However,
patent applications, grants, renewals and expiries are all more meaningful when
pegged to something, preferably
repeating the exercise at regular intervals in order to build up a set of
impressions that have some trajectory through time as well as space.
Once we have our data, our
correlations, our causations and an image of the patent system which is
historical, current and, to the extent that it can be projected, future-facing,
we can either use it in order to make better decisions as to how the patent
system works or, if the mood takes us, we can continue to run the system by
taking decisions that are essentially political in nature but have a better
idea as to what might happen if we do.
No comments:
Post a Comment