A European Commission DG Growth initiative described in its Roadmap on Standard Essential Patents for
a European digitalised economy aims to increase information on SEPs
so implementers can get a better idea about which of these they might be
infringing. Additional disclosures on how patent claims might read on the standards
could be beneficial. Requirements should reflect the dynamics and uncertainties
in standards development and patent prosecution and must not be onerous to
patent owners. These are issues for standards development organisations to
consider.
A report DG Growth commissioned in support of its initiative entitled Transparency, Predictability, and
Efficiency of SSO-based Standardization and SEP Licensing (the CRA report) proposes that SDOs or
the European Patent Office could also help meet this objective by being appointinted the central assessor that would screen patent disclosures to determine and count which
patents are truly essential. This
would be undesirable intervention with various adverse consequences. As I wrote
here for IP Finance in detail very recently, third-party determinations on large
portfolios are inherently subjective, inconsistent and unreliable.
The creation of this EC-ordained “patent counting” database would also
lend it to being used as an interventionist means of valuing SEP portfolios. In
conjunction with the unwarranted imposition of maximum cumulative rates (i.e.
royalty caps), this could facilitate the ill-conceived price regulation
alluded to by the Competition Commissioner.
The CRA report also embraces defective patent hold-up and royalty
stacking theories. General theories on hold-up and “Cournot complements” are
misrepresented and do not apply to patents. There is a lack of supporting
evidence on alleged patent hold-up, royalty stacking and much of it to the contrary
including that for opposing effects from patent hold-out (i.e. patent trespass).
SDO IPR policies are commonly misrepresented with the bogus notion
that patent owners should be deprived a share of value from use of patents in
standards. Neither the economics nor the law is settled here. Sharing in the “gains
from trade” incentivises risky investments.
Private ordering has worked very well in 2G, 3G, 4G and it will
continue to work well in IoT including 5G. Prospects are no more uncertain now
than they were when these previous-generation standards were introduced and
helped transform the communications markets. Decades of fruitful progress
indicates it is not “too soon to tell” how things are playing out. By all
measures these markets are extraordinarily competitive and successful, with large
research and development investments, extensive resulting innovation, massive
growth in subscribers and data consumption, reducing quality-adjusted prices, and
dramatic shifts in market shares with new market entry, market exits, low and
decreasing concentration in supply. I have been showing this with facts and
figures here, here and here for many years, and as others have confirmed.
The CRA report is right to reject a mandatory switch to chip-based
royalty rates and licensing, and to recognise the legitimacy of charging
different royalties depending on “field-of-use” (e.g. an IoT lightbulb versus
an augmented reality headset or a self-driving car). This well-established
principle aligns costs with functionality used and value generated.
IoT is expected to be worth up to the teens
of trillions of dollars to the global economy by 2025. That is 500
times more than the cost of licensing the communications technologies that are
already providing the growth fulcrum for IoT developments. Undercutting royalties will diminish gains
that could otherwise be obtained widely by leveraging reinvestments in intellectual
property.
With it being much more difficult to obtain injunctions than it used
to be, as the CRA report and Justice Birss in Unwired Planet v. Huawei
also observes, the scales have already been tipped significantly in favour of
implementers versus technology developers in terms of bargaining power. The
balance here needs to be redressed here not swayed further. Royalties are flat
or declining while opportunities and demands to invest in R&D for the good
of all in IoT and 5G are increasing.
DG Growth should not interfere with SDO governance or try to pick
winners among these or their IPR policies. Rather than speculating about how
much aggregate licensing costs could be, costs should be measured by asking
licensees what they are actually paying in cash royalties. Compare that with
the value the resulting technologies deliver in the market.
Private ordering is preferable to public ordering and intervention is unnecessary. SDOs,
patent pools, other licensing platforms and bilateral licensing under FRAND
conditions can continue to serve the industry well and to the benefit of consumers.
However, if EC decides to intervene there should be impact assessments
before intervening and empirical analysis of effects thereafter. DG
Growth should also measure the results previous rulings— including those
affecting the availability of injunctions— have already had on royalty rates
and how long it takes to complete licensing agreements.
DG Growth’s analysis should be as open and transparent as possible, for
scrutiny by all.
The above is a summary to my full article, here. This supplements my response to the DG Growth consultation
on this topic in 2015.
No comments:
Post a Comment